Price Discrimination and Monopoly Nonlinear Pricing Chapter 6

  • Slides: 30
Download presentation
Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1

Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1

Introduction • Annual subscriptions generally cost less in total than one-off purchases • Buying

Introduction • Annual subscriptions generally cost less in total than one-off purchases • Buying in bulk usually offers a price discount – these are price discrimination reflecting quantity discounts – prices are nonlinear, with the unit price dependent upon the quantity bought – allows pricing nearer to willingness to pay – so should be more profitable than third-degree price discrimination • How to design such pricing schemes? – depends upon the information available to the seller about buyers – distinguish first-degree (personalized) and second-degree (menu) pricing Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 2

First-degree price discrimination 2 • Monopolist can charge maximum price that each consumer is

First-degree price discrimination 2 • Monopolist can charge maximum price that each consumer is willing to pay • Extracts all consumer surplus • Since profit is now total surplus, find that first-degree price discrimination is efficient Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 3

First-degree price discrimination 3 • Suppose that you own five antique cars • Market

First-degree price discrimination 3 • Suppose that you own five antique cars • Market research shows there are collectors of different types – keenest is willing to pay $10, 000 for a car, second keenest $8, 000, third keenest $6, 000, fourth keenest $4, 000, fifth keenest $2, 000 – sell the first car at $10, 000 – sell the second car at $8, 000 – sell the third car to at $6, 000 and so on – total revenue $30, 000 • Contrast with linear pricing: all cars sold at the same price – set a price of $6, 000 – sell three cars – total revenue $18, 000 Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 4

First-degree price discrimination 4 • First-degree price discrimination is highly profitable but requires –

First-degree price discrimination 4 • First-degree price discrimination is highly profitable but requires – detailed information – ability to avoid arbitrage • Leads to the efficient choice of output: since price equals marginal revenue and MR = MC – no value-creating exchanges are missed Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 5

First-degree price discrimination 5 • The information requirements appear to be insurmountable – but

First-degree price discrimination 5 • The information requirements appear to be insurmountable – but not in particular cases • tax accountants, doctors, students applying to private universities • No arbitrage is less restrictive but potentially a problem • But there are pricing schemes that will achieve the same outcome – non-linear prices – two-part pricing as a particular example of non-linear prices • charge a quantity-independent fee (membership? ) plus a per unit usage charge – block pricing is another • bundle total charge and quantity in a package Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 6

Two-part pricing • Jazz club serves two types of customer – Old: demand for

Two-part pricing • Jazz club serves two types of customer – Old: demand for entry plus Qo drinks is P = Vo – Qo – Young: demand for entry plus Qy drinks is P = Vy – Qy – Equal numbers of each type – Assume that Vo > Vy: Old are willing to pay more than Young – Cost of operating the jazz club C(Q) = F + c. Q • Demand costs are all in daily units Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 7

Two-part pricing 2 • Suppose that the jazz club owner applies “traditional” linear pricing:

Two-part pricing 2 • Suppose that the jazz club owner applies “traditional” linear pricing: free entry and a set price for drinks – – – – – aggregate demand is Q = Qo + Qy = (Vo + Vy) – 2 P invert to give: P = (Vo + Vy)/2 – Q/2 MR is then MR = (Vo + Vy)/2 – Q equate MR and MC, where MC = c and solve for Q to give QU = (Vo + Vy)/2 – c substitute into aggregate demand to give the equilibrium price PU = (Vo + Vy)/4 + c/2 each Old consumer buys Qo = (3 Vo – Vy)/4 – c/2 drinks each Young consumer buys Qy = (3 Vy – Vo)/4 – c/2 drinks profit from each pair of Old and Young is U = (Vo + Vy – 2 c)2 Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 8

Two part pricing 3 This example can be illustrated as follows: (a) Old Customers

Two part pricing 3 This example can be illustrated as follows: (a) Old Customers Price Vo (b) Young Customers Price Vo a V d (c) Old/Young Pair of Customers y b g e f Vo+V y + c h 4 2 i c k j MC MR Quantity Vo Quantity Vy Vo+V y 2 -c Quantity Vo + Vy Linear pricing leaves each type of consumer with consumer surplus Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 9

Two part pricing 4 • Jazz club owner can do better than this •

Two part pricing 4 • Jazz club owner can do better than this • Consumer surplus at the uniform linear price is: – Old: CSo = (Vo – PU). Qo/2 = (Qo)2/2 – Young: CSy = (Vy – PU). Qy/2 = (Qy)2/2 • So charge an entry fee (just less than): – Eo = CSo to each Old customer and Ey = CSy to each Young customer • check IDs to implement this policy – each type will still be willing to frequent the club and buy the equilibrium number of drinks • So this increases profit by Eo for each Old and Ey for each Young customer Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 10

Two part pricing 5 • The jazz club can do even better – reduce

Two part pricing 5 • The jazz club can do even better – reduce the price per drink – this increases consumer surplus – but the additional consumer surplus can be extracted through a higher entry fee • Consider the best that the jazz club owner can do with respect to each type of consumer Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 11

Two-Part Pricing $/unit Vi Set the unit price equal to marginal cost This gives

Two-Part Pricing $/unit Vi Set the unit price equal to marginal cost This gives consumer surplus of (Vi - c)2/2 The entry charge Using two-part converts consumer pricing surplus increases the into profit monopolist’s profit c MC MR Set the entry charge to (Vi - c)2/2 Vi - c Vi Quantity Profit from each pair of Old and Young now d = [(Vo – c)2 + (Vy – c)2]/2 Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 12

Block pricing • There is another pricing method that the club owner can apply

Block pricing • There is another pricing method that the club owner can apply – offer a package of “Entry plus X drinks for $Y” • To maximize profit apply two rules – set the quantity offered to each consumer type equal to the amount that type would buy at price equal to marginal cost – set the total charge for each consumer type to the total willingness to pay for the relevant quantity • Return to the example: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 13

Block pricing 2 $ Vo Old $ Willingness to pay of each Old customer

Block pricing 2 $ Vo Old $ Willingness to pay of each Old customer Quantity supplied to each Old customer c MC Qo Quantity Vy Young Willingness to pay of each Young customer Quantity supplied to each Young customer c Vo MC Qy Vy Quantity WTPo = (Vo – c)2/2 + (Vo – c)c = (Vo 2 – c 2)/2 WTPy = (Vy – c)2/2 + (Vy – c)c = (Vy 2 – c 2)/2 Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 14

Block pricing 3 • How to implement this policy? – card at the door

Block pricing 3 • How to implement this policy? – card at the door – give customers the requisite number of tokens that are exchanged for drinks Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 15

A final comment • One final point – average price that is paid by

A final comment • One final point – average price that is paid by an Old customer = (Vo 2 – c 2)/2(Vo – c) = (Vo + c)/2 – average price paid by a Young customer = (Vy 2 – c 2)/2(Vo – c) = (Vy + c)/2 – identical to the third-degree price discrimination (linear) prices – but the profit outcome is much better with first-degree price discrimination. Why? • consumer equates MC of last unit bought with marginal benefit • with linear pricing MC = AC (= average price) • with first-degree price discrimination MC of last unit bought is less than AC (= average price) so more is bought Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 16

Second-degree price discrimination • What if the seller cannot distinguish between buyers? – perhaps

Second-degree price discrimination • What if the seller cannot distinguish between buyers? – perhaps they differ in income (unobservable) • Then the type of price discrimination just discussed is impossible • High-income buyer will pretend to be a low-income buyer – to avoid the high entry price – to pay the smaller total charge • Take a specific example – Ph = 16 – Qh – Pl = 12 – Ql – MC = 4 Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 17

Second-degree price discrimination 2 • First-degree price discrimination requires: – High Income: entry fee

Second-degree price discrimination 2 • First-degree price discrimination requires: – High Income: entry fee $72 and $4 per drink or entry plus 12 drinks for a total charge of $120 – Low Income: entry fee $32 and $4 per drink or entry plus 8 drinks for total charge of $64 • This will not work – high income types get no consumer surplus from the package designed for them but get consumer surplus from the other package – so they will pretend to be low income even if this limits the number of drinks they can buy • Need to design a “menu” of offerings targeted at the two types Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 18

Second-degree price discrimination 3 • The seller has to compromise • Design a pricing

Second-degree price discrimination 3 • The seller has to compromise • Design a pricing scheme that makes buyers – reveal their true types – self-select the quantity/price package designed for them • Essence of second-degree price discrimination • It is “like” first-degree price discrimination – the seller knows that there are buyers of different types – but the seller is not able to identify the different types • A two-part tariff is ineffective – allows deception by buyers • Use quantity discounting Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 19

Low income consumers will not buy the ($88, 12) High-income Low-Income package since they

Low income consumers will not buy the ($88, 12) High-income Low-Income package since they These packages exhibit This is the incentive are willing to pay highquantity discounting: So any other package So will the high. The low-demand consumers will be only $72 forper 12 unit compatibility constraint income pay $7. 33 and income consumers: offered to high-income willing to buy this ($64, 8) package drinks low-income pay $8 So they can be offered a package because consumers the ($64, 8) must $ - offer at High income consumers are Profit of from ($88, each 12) (since high$120 32 = 88) And profit from package gives them $32 willing to pay up to $120 for least $32 income consumer and theyconsumer is will buy thissurplus each low-income consumer surplus Offer the low-income 12 entry plus 12 drinks if no other $40 ($88 - 12 x $4) consumer aispackage of consumers package is available $32 entry($64 plus- 88 x$4) drinks for $64 Second degree price discrimination 4 $ 16 8 4 $32 $40 $64 $32 $8 $24 $32 MC $16 8 12 Quantity 4 MC $32 16 Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing $8 8 12 Quantity 20

Second degree price discrimination 5 A high-income consumer will pay High-Income up to $87.

Second degree price discrimination 5 A high-income consumer will pay High-Income up to $87. 50 for entry and 7 The monopolist does better by drinks So buying the ($59. 50, 7) package Suppose each low-income reducing the number of units gives him $28 consumer surplus consumer is offered 7 drinks offered to low-income consumers Can thebeclub. So entry plus 12 drinks can sold Each consumer will pay up to Low-Income for each $92 ($120 -12) 28 allows = $92) since this him to increase owner do $even $59. 50 for entry and 7 drinks Profit from ($92, $ 16 package is $44: an increase of $4 the charge to this? high-income Yes! Reduce the number Profit from each ($59. 50, 7) better than 12 per consumer package is $31. 50: reduction of units offered toaeach consumers of $0. 50 per consumer low-income consumer $28 4 $87. 50 $44$92 MC $28$48 4 $31. 50 $59. 50 MC $28 7 12 Quantity 16 Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 7 8 12 Quantity 21

Second-degree price discrimination 6 • Will the monopolist always want to supply both types

Second-degree price discrimination 6 • Will the monopolist always want to supply both types of consumer? • There are cases where it is better to supply only highdemand types – high-class restaurants – golf and country clubs • Take our example again – suppose that there are Nl low-income consumers – and Nh high-income consumers Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 22

Second-degree price discrimination 7 • Suppose both types of consumer are served – two

Second-degree price discrimination 7 • Suppose both types of consumer are served – two packages are offered ($57. 50, 7) aimed at low-income and ($92, 12) aimed at high-income – profit is $31. 50 x. Nl + $44 x. Nh • Now suppose only high-income consumers are served – then a ($120, 12) package can be offered – profit is $72 x. Nh • Is it profitable to serve both types? – Only if $31. 50 x. Nl + $44 x. Nh > $72 x. Nh 31. 50 Nl > 28 Nh This requires that Nh < 31. 50 = 1. 125 Nl 28 There should not be “too high” a fraction of high-demand consumers Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 23

Second-degree price discrimination 8 • Characteristics of second-degree price discrimination – extract all consumer

Second-degree price discrimination 8 • Characteristics of second-degree price discrimination – extract all consumer surplus from the lowest-demand group – leave some consumer surplus for other groups • the incentive compatibility constraint – offer less than the socially efficient quantity to all groups other than the highest-demand group – offer quantity-discounting • Second-degree price discrimination converts consumer surplus into profit less effectively than first-degree • Some consumer surplus is left “on the table” in order to induce high-demand groups to buy large quantities Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 24

Non-linear pricing and welfare • Non-linear price discrimination raises profit • Does it increase

Non-linear pricing and welfare • Non-linear price discrimination raises profit • Does it increase social welfare? – suppose that inverse demand of consumer group i is P = Pi(Q) – marginal cost is constant at MC – c – suppose quantity offered to consumer group i is Qi – total surplus – consumer surplus profit –is the area between the inverse demand marginal cost up to quantity Qi Price Demand Total Surplus c MC Qi Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing Qi(c) Quantity 25

Non-linear pricing and welfare 2 • Pricing policy affects – distribution of surplus –

Non-linear pricing and welfare 2 • Pricing policy affects – distribution of surplus – output of the firm • • First is welfare neutral Second affects welfare Does it increase social welfare? Price discrimination increases social welfare of group i if it increases quantity supplied to group i Price Demand Total Surplus c MC Qi Q’i Qi(c) Quantity Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 26

Non-linear pricing and welfare 3 • First-degree price discrimination always increases social welfare –

Non-linear pricing and welfare 3 • First-degree price discrimination always increases social welfare – extracts all consumer surplus – but generates socially optimal output – output to group i is Qi(c) – this exceeds output with uniform (nondiscriminatory) pricing Price Demand Total Surplus c MC Qi Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing Qi(c) Quantity 27

Non-linear pricing and welfare 4 • Menu pricing is less straightforward Price – suppose

Non-linear pricing and welfare 4 • Menu pricing is less straightforward Price – suppose that there are two markets • low demand • high demand PU • Uniform price is PU • Menu pricing gives quantities Q 1 s, s Q • 2 Welfare loss is greater than L • Welfare gain is less than G Low demand offered less than the socially optimal quantity L MC Qls Ql. U Quantity Price High demand offered the socially optimal quantity PU G Qh. U Qhs Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing MC Quantity 28

Non-linear pricing and welfare 5 Price • It follows that ΔW < G –

Non-linear pricing and welfare 5 Price • It follows that ΔW < G – L = (PU – MC)ΔQ 1 + (PU – MC)ΔQ 2 = (PU – MC)(ΔQ 1 + ΔQ 2) PU • A necessary condition for seconddegree price discrimination to Price increase social welfare is that it increases total output • “Like” third-degree price discrimination • But second-degree price discrimination P is more likely to increase output U L MC Qls Ql. U Quantity G Qh. U Qhs Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing MC Quantity 29

The incentive compatibility constraint • Any offer made to high demand consumers must offer

The incentive compatibility constraint • Any offer made to high demand consumers must offer them as much consumer surplus as they would get from an offer designed for low-demand consumers. • This is a common phenomenon – performance bonuses must encourage effort – insurance policies need large deductibles to deter cheating – piece rates in factories have to be accompanied by strict quality inspection – encouragement to buy in bulk must offer a price discount Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 30