Measuring Income Inequality Measuring Income Inequality The extent

  • Slides: 20
Download presentation
Measuring Income Inequality

Measuring Income Inequality

Measuring Income Inequality • The extent of income concentration within a country or group.

Measuring Income Inequality • The extent of income concentration within a country or group. • In many countries in the Middle East there is a high income per capita relative to other countries in the world. However, whilst the average person is better off such a statistic tells you nothing of the distribution of income within the country. • Principles of Inequality Measurement (Ray, 1998, pp. 174178)

Measuring Income Inequality (1) Anonymity Principle: permutations of incomes amongst ‘n’ people should not

Measuring Income Inequality (1) Anonymity Principle: permutations of incomes amongst ‘n’ people should not matter for inequality measures, so that (2) Population Principle: the size of a country’s population is unimportant but what is important is the proportions of the population that earn different levels of income. (3) Relative Income Principle: it is not the absolute level of income that is important to inequality but the relative size of incomes.

Measuring Income Inequality E. G. If Thabo has $1 and Tshepo has $2, then

Measuring Income Inequality E. G. If Thabo has $1 and Tshepo has $2, then Tshepo has twice as much as Thabo or has 2/3 rds of all the income. If Thabo has $1500 and Tshepo has $2000 then Tshepo has 4/7 th of total income and income inequality between the two has declined. The Dalton Principle: If Distribution ‘A’ can be achieved from Distribution ‘B’ by constructing a sequence of regressive (from poor to rich) transfers then A is more unequal than B. The issue of whether income inequality changes with growth and development or whether initial income inequality is important to sustainable growth is discussed in the Pro-Poor growth lecture.

Measuring Income Inequality The Gini Coefficient: • The ‘Gini’ is based on the income

Measuring Income Inequality The Gini Coefficient: • The ‘Gini’ is based on the income levels of individuals. • Assume there are ‘m’ distinct income groups, each income group is denoted by ‘j’ but there are ‘m’ such groups. • Within each income group ‘j’ there a number of individuals earning that income level. The total number of people ‘n’ is equal to

Measuring Income Inequality • The average/mean of any income (y) distribution is denoted by

Measuring Income Inequality • The average/mean of any income (y) distribution is denoted by This average is simply the total income of all individuals divided by the number of individuals. Hence,

Measuring Income Inequality • The Gini coefficient does not take the difference between individual

Measuring Income Inequality • The Gini coefficient does not take the difference between individual income and the mean income as would be done if estimating the coefficient of variation. • Instead the Gini calculates the income differences between all pairs of incomes. These differences are then summed together with absolute values being used so that information is not lost through values being both positive and negative. • The income differences are paired and are counted twice. (Q) Why? Well, as well as taking the difference between income of individual ‘j’ and individual ‘k’, so that = income difference

Measuring Income Inequality • Clearly the differences in income will be identical with opposite

Measuring Income Inequality • Clearly the differences in income will be identical with opposite signs. Since we take absolute values of income differences, we could estimate one of the differences and multiply by a factor of 2. • The Gini coefficient is represented by, • There are 2 summations because firstly we sum over all the ks holding each j constant, and then we do the same for the js, summing over all the js holding each k constant. • Essentially we are summing every single income differential in the sample. So everything inside the brackets represents the sum of the income differentials for the whole sample.

Measuring Income Inequality • This large number is then divided by. The ‘ 2’

Measuring Income Inequality • This large number is then divided by. The ‘ 2’ comes from counting income differentials twice when summing over ‘ks’ and then ‘js’. The and the mean income terms are included so as to normalize the Gini coefficient. • The Gini coefficient is good at picking up increasing or decreasing income inequality. For example, transfers of income from a low-income person to a highincome person would mean that the income differential between these two persons would increase, meaning the Gini coefficient would increase reflecting increasing income inequality. • The Gini coefficient is also related to the Lorenz curve in a diagrammatical way. The Gini is actually equivalent to the area between the 45 degree line and the Lorenz curve divided by the entire area beneath the 45 degree line. Hence, the higher the Gini the more ‘bowed’ the Lorenz curve and the higher the degree of income inequality.

Measuring Income Inequality Example of calculating a Gini Coefficient. South Africa is assumed to

Measuring Income Inequality Example of calculating a Gini Coefficient. South Africa is assumed to have 6 people earning respectively, R 1000, R 15000, R 150, R 100 The Gini Coefficient here is? Firstly we must calculate the income differences for each j and k. . Thus, (R 1000 -R 100)=R 900 (R 1000 -15000)= -R 14000 (R 1000 -R 150)=R 850 (R 1000 -R 50)=R 950 (R 1000 -R 100)=R 900 for • Then do the same for each other income differential and sum for both j and k. The summation term should be equal to R 147, 200. The mean income for SA is R 2733. • The Gini coefficient is equal to 0. 748. This illustrates a high degree of income inequality within SA. (Whilst these numbers are made up, in reality the income distribution in South Africa is amongst the highest in the world as we will see later).

Measuring Income Inequality The Lorenz Curve • Is a diagram to explain income inequality

Measuring Income Inequality The Lorenz Curve • Is a diagram to explain income inequality in a country. • Is based on two pieces of information, income and population. • Information is required on both and then formed into two variables that reflect the cumulative value of income and the population. • On the horizontal axis we sort the cumulative population in the ascending order of income, with the lowest income first followed by the second lowest and so on. Hence the first 20% of the population will necessarily be the poorest 20% of the entire population. • NOTE: Of importance here is to understand that incomes of peoples must be placed in ascending order with the poorest first, followed by second poorest………. . up to the richest household/family/person in the country.

Measuring Income Inequality • In a perfectly egalitarian society there would be no difference

Measuring Income Inequality • In a perfectly egalitarian society there would be no difference in cumulative income levels between the bottom 20% and the top 20% or any other 20% since all income is distributed equally. • This is a kind of utopia, and is represented in Figure 1 by the straight line which is a 45 degree line, or put another way has a gradient of +1, a 1% increase in the population is everywhere equal to a 1% increase in cumulative income. • In reality every country has a different Lorenz curve with none being egalitarian!!!!

Measuring Income Inequality • In reality the Lorenz curve is away and to the

Measuring Income Inequality • In reality the Lorenz curve is away and to the right of the egalitarian curve. • The further the curve is away from the 45 degree line the more unequal the country’s distribution of income is. • The Lorenz curve shown in Figure 1 illustrates that the poorest 40% of the population instead of having 40% of the country’s income actually has just 9% of the country’s income! • By comparison, when we look at the top 20% of the country’s population (the richest 20%) we see that instead of them having 20% of income they actually control 65% of the country’s income! • Put another way you can say the poorest 80% of the country’s population control 35% of the income. • Note that the area between the 45 degree line and the Lorenz curve forms the numerator of the Gini coefficient, with the denominator being equivalent to the area below the 45 degree line.

Measuring Income Inequality • The issue to be aware of in estimating Lorenz curves

Measuring Income Inequality • The issue to be aware of in estimating Lorenz curves is that for different years for the same country the curves can cross, making interpretation problematic. Example from Ray (1998, pp. 183). • • Group 1: 6 people with incomes, 25, 175, 300, 350, 600, 1500 = 2950 Group 2: 6 people with incomes, 50, 80, 200, 600, 820, 1200 = 2950 • You can plot these distributions and calculate Lorenz curves for both groups, by calculating the cumulative percentage of each income value in terms of the total income for each group. • The Lorenz curves cross. Means that we can get from Group 2 to Group 1 by both progressive (from rich to poor) and regressive (from poor to rich) travels……. . interpretation and hence policy becomes problematic and if this does arise in a country then must investigate at a more micro level!!!

Measuring Income Inequality Other Income Inequality Indices Entropy Measures E. g. Theil Index See

Measuring Income Inequality Other Income Inequality Indices Entropy Measures E. g. Theil Index See www. worldbank. org/poverty/inequal/dddeisqo. htm. The entropy measures have the desirable property of being decomposable so that inequality within a group (intra-group inequality) and between groups (inter-group inequality) can be estimated. This can have important implications for policy makers.

Measuring Income Inequality Other Income Inequality Measures Theil Index – Entropy Measure. Entropy means

Measuring Income Inequality Other Income Inequality Measures Theil Index – Entropy Measure. Entropy means ‘disorder’ – deviations from perfect income equality. The basic form of the Thiel Index is

Measuring Income Inequality Theil Index cont… Where is income of individual ‘i’, and is

Measuring Income Inequality Theil Index cont… Where is income of individual ‘i’, and is the average income of the population, ‘n’. Can calculate the Theil Index from given income per capita data.

Measuring Income Inequality Theil Index cont… Individual (1) Income (2) 1 Average Income (3)

Measuring Income Inequality Theil Index cont… Individual (1) Income (2) 1 Average Income (3) Ratio of income to average income (4) Log (ratio of income to average income) (5) (6)=(4) x (5) 300 0. 170 -0. 768 -0. 131 2 500 0. 284 -0. 547 -0. 155 3 1000 0. 568 -0. 246 -0. 139 4 2000 1. 136 0. 056 0. 063 5 5000 2. 841 0. 453 1. 288 1760 Sum of values = 0. 926 Theil Index is sum of 6 divided by observations 0. 185

Measuring Income Inequality Theil Index cont… Can decompose the Theil index into between group

Measuring Income Inequality Theil Index cont… Can decompose the Theil index into between group inequality and within group inequality. E. g. Look at income inequality within racial groups and then between racial groups. Practically this entails estimating Theil index for each of the racial groups and then summing them according to some weight (e. g. population weight) to give total within-race inequality, Tw. Then calculate the Theil using the ratio of average income for each racial group/average income of entire population to give between race income inequality, Tb. Add the two together for overall Theil index = Tw+Tb See “Describing Income Inequality Theil Index and Entropy Class Indexes” by Lorenzo Giovanni Bellù, and Paolo Liberati, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, FAO.

References Bellu, L. , and Liberati, P. , (2006), “Describing Income Inequality Theil Index

References Bellu, L. , and Liberati, P. , (2006), “Describing Income Inequality Theil Index and Entropy Class Indexes”, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, FAO. Ray, D. , (1998), Development Economics, Princeton University Press. Foster, Greer and Thorbecke (1984), “A class of decomposable poverty measures”, Econometrica, Vol 52(3), pp. 761 -6. Foster and Shorrocks (1988), “Poverty Orderings”, Econometrica, Vol 56, pp. 173 -7. Atkinson (1987), “On the Measurement of Poverty”, Econometrica, Vol 55(4), pp. 749 -64.