Chapter 10 Intertemporal Choice Intertemporal Choice u Persons

  • Slides: 69
Download presentation
Chapter 10 Intertemporal Choice

Chapter 10 Intertemporal Choice

Intertemporal Choice u Persons often receive income in “lumps”; e. g. monthly salary. u

Intertemporal Choice u Persons often receive income in “lumps”; e. g. monthly salary. u How is a lump of income spread over the following month (saving now for consumption later)? u Or how is consumption financed by borrowing now against income to be received at the end of the month?

Present and Future Values u Begin with some simple financial arithmetic. u Take just

Present and Future Values u Begin with some simple financial arithmetic. u Take just two periods; 1 and 2. u Let r denote the interest rate period.

Future Value u E. g. , if r = 0. 1 then $100 saved

Future Value u E. g. , if r = 0. 1 then $100 saved at the start of period 1 becomes $110 at the start of period 2. u The value next period of $1 saved now is the future value of that dollar.

Future Value u Given an interest rate r the future value one period from

Future Value u Given an interest rate r the future value one period from now of $1 is u Given an interest rate r the future value one period from now of $m is

Present Value u Suppose you can pay now to obtain $1 at the start

Present Value u Suppose you can pay now to obtain $1 at the start of next period. u What is the most you should pay? u $1? u No. If you kept your $1 now and saved it then at the start of next period you would have $(1+r) > $1, so paying $1 now for $1 next period is a bad deal.

Present Value u Q: How much money would have to be saved now, in

Present Value u Q: How much money would have to be saved now, in the present, to obtain $1 at the start of the next period? u A: $m saved now becomes $m(1+r) at the start of next period, so we want the value of m for which m(1+r) = 1 That is, m = 1/(1+r), the present-value of $1 obtained at the start of next period.

Present Value u The present value of $1 available at the start of the

Present Value u The present value of $1 available at the start of the next period is u And the present value of $m available at the start of the next period is

Present Value u E. g. , if r = 0. 1 then the most

Present Value u E. g. , if r = 0. 1 then the most you should pay now for $1 available next period is u And if r = 0. 2 then the most you should pay now for $1 available next period is

The Intertemporal Choice Problem u Let m 1 and m 2 be incomes received

The Intertemporal Choice Problem u Let m 1 and m 2 be incomes received in periods 1 and 2. u Let c 1 and c 2 be consumptions in periods 1 and 2. u Let p 1 and p 2 be the prices of consumption in periods 1 and 2.

The Intertemporal Choice Problem u The intertemporal choice problem: Given incomes m 1 and

The Intertemporal Choice Problem u The intertemporal choice problem: Given incomes m 1 and m 2, and given consumption prices p 1 and p 2, what is the most preferred intertemporal consumption bundle (c 1, c 2)? u For an answer we need to know: – the intertemporal budget constraint – intertemporal consumption preferences.

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u To start, let’s ignore price effects by supposing that

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u To start, let’s ignore price effects by supposing that p 1 = p 2 = $1.

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Suppose that the consumer chooses not to save or

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Suppose that the consumer chooses not to save or to borrow. u Q: What will be consumed in period 1? u A: c 1 = m 1. u Q: What will be consumed in period 2? u A: c 2 = m 2.

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 m 2 0 0 m 1 c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 m 2 0 0 m 1 c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 So (c 1, c 2) = (m 1,

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 So (c 1, c 2) = (m 1, m 2) is the consumption bundle if the consumer chooses neither to save nor to borrow. m 2 0 0 m 1 c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Now suppose that the consumer spends nothing on consumption

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Now suppose that the consumer spends nothing on consumption in period 1; that is, c 1 = 0 and the consumer saves s 1 = m 1. u The interest rate is r. u What now will be period 2’s consumption level?

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Period 2 income is m 2. u Savings plus

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Period 2 income is m 2. u Savings plus interest from period 1 sum to (1 + r )m 1. u So total income available in period 2 is m 2 + (1 + r )m 1. u So period 2 consumption expenditure is

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Period 2 income is m 2. u Savings plus

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Period 2 income is m 2. u Savings plus interest from period 1 sum to (1 + r )m 1. u So total income available in period 2 is m 2 + (1 + r )m 1. u So period 2 consumption expenditure is

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 the future-value of the income endowment m 2

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 the future-value of the income endowment m 2 0 0 m 1 c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 is the consumption bundle when all period 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 is the consumption bundle when all period 1 income is saved. m 2 0 0 m 1 c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Now suppose that the consumer spends everything possible on

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Now suppose that the consumer spends everything possible on consumption in period 1, so c 2 = 0. u What is the most that the consumer can borrow in period 1 against her period 2 income of $m 2? u Let b 1 denote the amount borrowed in period 1.

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Only $m 2 will be available in period 2

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Only $m 2 will be available in period 2 to pay back $b 1 borrowed in period 1. u So b 1(1 + r ) = m 2. u That is, b 1 = m 2 / (1 + r ). u So the largest possible period 1 consumption level is

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Only $m 2 will be available in period 2

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Only $m 2 will be available in period 2 to pay back $b 1 borrowed in period 1. u So b 1(1 + r ) = m 2. u That is, b 1 = m 2 / (1 + r ). u So the largest possible period 1 consumption level is

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 is the consumption bundle when all period 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 is the consumption bundle when all period 1 income is saved. the present-value of the income endowment m 2 0 0 m 1 c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 is the consumption bundle when period 1 saving

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 is the consumption bundle when period 1 saving is as large as possible. m 2 0 0 is the consumption bundle when period 1 borrowing is as big as possible. m 1 c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Suppose that c 1 units are consumed in period

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Suppose that c 1 units are consumed in period 1. This costs $c 1 and leaves m 1 - c 1 saved. Period 2 consumption will then be

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Suppose that c 1 units are consumed in period

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Suppose that c 1 units are consumed in period 1. This costs $c 1 and leaves m 1 - c 1 saved. Period 2 consumption will then be slope intercept î í ì ìï í ï î which is

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 is the consumption bundle when period 1 saving

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 is the consumption bundle when period 1 saving is as large as possible. m 2 0 0 is the consumption bundle when period 1 borrowing is as big as possible. m 1 c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 slope = -(1+r) m 2 0 0 m

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 slope = -(1+r) m 2 0 0 m 1 c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 slope = -(1+r) Sa vi m 2 0

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 slope = -(1+r) Sa vi m 2 0 0 ng Bo rro wi m 1 ng c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint is the “future-valued” form of the budget constraint since all

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint is the “future-valued” form of the budget constraint since all terms are in period 2 values. This is equivalent to which is the “present-valued” form of the constraint since all terms are in period 1 values.

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Now let’s add prices p 1 and p 2

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint u Now let’s add prices p 1 and p 2 for consumption in periods 1 and 2. u How does this affect the budget constraint?

Intertemporal Choice u Given her endowment (m 1, m 2) and prices p 1,

Intertemporal Choice u Given her endowment (m 1, m 2) and prices p 1, p 2 what intertemporal consumption bundle (c 1*, c 2*) will be chosen by the consumer? u Maximum possible expenditure in period 2 is so maximum possible consumption in period 2 is

Intertemporal Choice u Similarly, maximum possible expenditure in period 1 is so maximum possible

Intertemporal Choice u Similarly, maximum possible expenditure in period 1 is so maximum possible consumption in period 1 is

Intertemporal Choice u Finally, if c 1 units are consumed in period 1 then

Intertemporal Choice u Finally, if c 1 units are consumed in period 1 then the consumer spends p 1 c 1 in period 1, leaving m 1 - p 1 c 1 saved for period 1. Available income in period 2 will then be so

Intertemporal Choice rearranged is This is the “future-valued” form of the budget constraint since

Intertemporal Choice rearranged is This is the “future-valued” form of the budget constraint since all terms are expressed in period 2 values. Equivalent to it is the “present-valued” form where all terms are expressed in period 1 values.

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1 c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1 c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1 c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 Slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 m

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 Slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1 c 1

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 Sa vi m 2/p 2 0 0 ng

The Intertemporal Budget Constraint c 2 Sa vi m 2/p 2 0 0 ng Slope = Bo rro wi m 1/p 1 ng c 1

Price Inflation u Define u For the inflation rate by p where example, p

Price Inflation u Define u For the inflation rate by p where example, p = 0. 2 means 20% inflation, and p = 1. 0 means 100% inflation.

Price Inflation u We lose nothing by setting p 1=1 so that p 2

Price Inflation u We lose nothing by setting p 1=1 so that p 2 = 1+ p. u Then we can rewrite the budget constraint as

Price Inflation rearranges to so the slope of the intertemporal budget constraint is

Price Inflation rearranges to so the slope of the intertemporal budget constraint is

Price Inflation u When there was no price inflation (p 1=p 2=1) the slope

Price Inflation u When there was no price inflation (p 1=p 2=1) the slope of the budget constraint was -(1+r). u Now, with price inflation, the slope of the budget constraint is -(1+r)/(1+ p). This can be written as r is known as the real interest rate.

Real Interest Rate gives For low inflation rates (p » 0), r » r

Real Interest Rate gives For low inflation rates (p » 0), r » r - p. For higher inflation rates this approximation becomes poor.

Real Interest Rate

Real Interest Rate

Comparative Statics u The slope of the budget constraint is constraint becomes flatter if

Comparative Statics u The slope of the budget constraint is constraint becomes flatter if the interest rate r falls or the inflation rate p rises (both decrease the real rate of interest).

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1 c 1

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1 c 1

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = The consumer saves. m 2/p 2 0 0

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = The consumer saves. m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1 c 1

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 The consumer saves.

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 The consumer saves. An increase in the inflation rate or a decrease in the interest rate “flattens” the budget constraint. m 1/p 1 c 1

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 If the consumer

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 If the consumer saves then saving and welfare reduced by a lower interest rate or a higher inflation rate. m 1/p 1 c 1

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1 c 1

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1 c 1

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = The consumer borrows. m 2/p 2 0 0

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = The consumer borrows. m 2/p 2 0 0 m 1/p 1 c 1

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 The consumer borrows.

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 The consumer borrows. A fall in the inflation rate or a rise in the interest rate “flattens” the budget constraint. m 1/p 1 c 1

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 If the consumer

Comparative Statics c 2 slope = m 2/p 2 0 0 If the consumer borrows then borrowing and welfare increased by a lower interest rate or a higher inflation rate. m 1/p 1 c 1

Valuing Securities u. A financial security is a financial instrument that promises to deliver

Valuing Securities u. A financial security is a financial instrument that promises to deliver an income stream. u E. g. ; a security that pays $m 1 at the end of year 1, $m 2 at the end of year 2, and $m 3 at the end of year 3. u What is the most that should be paid now for this security?

Valuing Securities u The security is equivalent to the sum of three securities; –

Valuing Securities u The security is equivalent to the sum of three securities; – the first pays only $m 1 at the end of year 1, – the second pays only $m 2 at the end of year 2, and – the third pays only $m 3 at the end of year 3.

Valuing Securities u The PV of $m 1 paid 1 year from now is

Valuing Securities u The PV of $m 1 paid 1 year from now is u The PV of $m 2 paid 2 years from now is u The PV of $m 3 paid 3 years from now is u The PV of the security is therefore

Valuing Bonds u. A bond is a special type of security that pays a

Valuing Bonds u. A bond is a special type of security that pays a fixed amount $x for T years (its maturity date) and then pays its face value $F. u What is the most that should now be paid for such a bond?

Valuing Bonds

Valuing Bonds

Valuing Bonds u Suppose you win a State lottery. The prize is $1, 000

Valuing Bonds u Suppose you win a State lottery. The prize is $1, 000 but it is paid over 10 years in equal installments of $100, 000 each. What is the prize actually worth?

Valuing Bonds is the actual (present) value of the prize.

Valuing Bonds is the actual (present) value of the prize.

Valuing Consols u. A consol is a bond which never terminates, paying $x period

Valuing Consols u. A consol is a bond which never terminates, paying $x period forever. u What is a consol’s present-value?

Valuing Consols

Valuing Consols

Valuing Consols Solving for PV gives

Valuing Consols Solving for PV gives

Valuing Consols E. g. if r = 0. 1 now and forever then the

Valuing Consols E. g. if r = 0. 1 now and forever then the most that should be paid now for a console that provides $1000 per year is